Friday 5 June 2015

Austerity will kill the economy




The Household Analogy

The last government failed to fix the roof when the sun was shining.  This was the diagnosis offered by incoming Chancellor George Osborne in 2010.  Now, a new government would be forced to take hard decisions that would be all the more painful.  And, echoing his ideological mistress, Osborne trotted out TINA – There Is No Alternative.

Of course, Osborne was helped by the idiotic note left by outgoing New Labour Chief Secretary to the Treasury Liam Byrne, proclaiming that “I’m afraid there is no money”.  And the remnants of New Labour in opposition quickly signed up to the Tory narrative and the austerity policies visited on the British people by the new ConDem coalition government.

For public consumption, the political leaders built upon the comely image of the small town householder working hard to keep a roof above his head.  The economy as a whole was portrayed as a household just like yours and mine.  If you or I borrow too much money, then we face hard choices.  We must either take a second job to bring in some more money or we must cut back on our spending.  Government, we were told, is exactly the same: “you cannot pay yourself more than you earn”.

Because the New Labour government had racked up huge levels of debt between 2008 and 2010, the only options available, they told us, were those that most householders would recognise – earn more money (i.e. stimulate private sector growth in order to increase tax yields) and cut back on outgoings (i.e. cut public spending programmes).  According to the new government, fortuitously, cutting public spending would clear the way for the private sector to grow.  So this would not be a real hardship.  While some people might lose their public sector jobs, these would soon be replaced by private sector employment.  So, in the long-term, everyone would benefit.

In practice, the policy has been catastrophic.  High-paid, high-skilled jobs have been lost in favour of low-paid, low-skilled jobs that are often part-time or zero-hours.  Wages outside the top five percent have stagnated, while the incomes of the most vulnerable – the working poor, the sick and disabled, people with mental illness, together with women who look after disabled children or older relatives – have fallen dramatically.  Private sector growth has been anaemic at best; with employment maintained only at the expense of falling productivity – leaving UK companies unable to compete in international markets. 

Public services are being hit by the unforeseen consequences of cuts.  For example, despite promising to protect the National Health Service, the government has succeeded in creating a series of crises in Accident and Emergency departments as a direct result of the cuts they made to adult social care services, which have removed many of the community-based beds where hospital patients would normally be moved once they were well enough.

For the foreseeable future we can expect even more of the same because both the Tories and the Labour opposition are signed up to the “economy as a household” narrative that dictates austerity as the only road back to prosperity.  For the most part, the majority of the 650 members of parliament, adopting this model of the economy is no more than idiocy – they simply do not know any better, and have never bothered to think about the problem.  For a handful, however, it is a cynical manipulation designed to dupe the public into accepting an ideological attack on social security and public services.  Because, whatever else our increasingly globalized economy is, it most certainly is not a household.

Even within a household, we might observe that working more and spending less are not the only options open to us.  We might, for example, consolidate our debts.  A household may have access to a credit card deal offering zero percent interest on an existing balance.  We could use this to “park” our debt until such time as our circumstances have improved enough to begin paying it off.  Government does not need a credit card.  It is able to borrow at close to zero percent interest anyway.  So, there is actually nothing to stop government from borrowing new loans at zero percent interest in order to pay off debt that currently attracts higher rates of interest.

There is, though, a critically important way in which government is unlike any household you or I have lived in – governments have printing presses.  If you or I were to try to solve our difficulties by using a good colour photocopier to print out counterfeit £20 notes, we would end up in jail.  This is because since 1844 it has been illegal for anyone other than the central bank to print money in the UK.  So one thing the government could do that a household cannot do is to print new money as an alternative to borrowing it.

Okay, we have heard this line before.  Wasn’t it Labour Prime Minister James Callaghan back in 1979 who told us that we could no longer print money to spend our way out of recession?  In those days, printing new money appeared to cause higher inflation.  So – and this is a key reason why the mainstream parties are signed up to austerity – if government today printed more money, wouldn’t this simply result in high inflation that would, ultimately, be worse than the privations of austerity?

Although we experience inflation as increasing prices, it is actually a form of currency devaluation.  Just as the Roman Emperors devalued their currency by reducing the quantities of gold and silver in the coins, allowing them to mint more, so in the modern world, printing more money without a corresponding growth in the economy can have the same effect – more money chasing the same goods and services leads to price increases.  To this, there is an important feedback mechanism – velocity.  If we expect prices to increase tomorrow, we are more likely to purchase today.  So, as inflation takes hold, the velocity (or rate) at which we spend increases.  This has a result similar to printing new money called the “multiplier effect”.  Suppose I earn an extra pound.  I might decide to spend it on some flowers for my wife.  This means that the florist now has an extra pound.  So the florist decides that when she goes for out a meal that evening, she will add the pound to the tip she leaves for the waiter.  The extra pound allows the waiter to take a taxi home.  The extra taxi fare allows the taxi driver to buy a magazine.  And so on.  One extra pound is spent over and over, having the effect of growing the amount of money in circulation at any time.

Now, the first thing to say about inflation is it is not necessarily a bad thing.  If you are a saver, inflation is a bad thing because you need to secure an interest rate that is at least the same as the rate of inflation just to break even.  But in the wider economy, we are better off if savers are encouraged to take risks, as this is the only way of encouraging investment in new (and potentially risky) business ventures.  So, inflation can help move investors’ money from unproductive asset speculation into productive capital investment.  If, on the other hand, you are a borrower, then inflation works for you by cutting the real value of the money you borrow.  When people take out mortgages, it is usually the first five years or so that are the most difficult.  Having borrowed some multiple of their earnings, they are committed to making that payment every month.  However, over time, as inflation increases, their wages increase accordingly.  But the monthly payment remains the same.  Over time, the mortgage gets easier and easier to pay off.  At a global level, the same is true of government debt.  As inflation increases, so government finds it easier to pay it off.

In any case, we should be very cautious about making comparisons with the way the national economy operated in the 1970s and the way the global economy operates today.  In this booklet I will make the case that the changes we have witnessed in the past thirty-five years make the comparison entirely unhelpful.  These changes have been so profound as to render the currency of today totally different to the money we used in the 1970s.  Indeed, one of the key failings of modern politics is the failure to understand this transformation.

In this booklet I will argue that in seeking to avoid the ghosts of the 1970s, modern policy makers are creating an even bigger crisis by generating a dangerous deflation in which money is destroyed and spending grinds to a halt.  In the face of a massively over-extended banking sector, this process – which is fuelled by austerity economics – threatens to bring the whole economic system crashing to the ground.

You can read the rest of Tim Watkins' new book, Austerity here.

No comments:

Post a Comment